When you can't live without bananas

Get email updates of new posts:        (Delivered by FeedBurner)

Sunday, February 18, 2024

Charging for Parking and Reduces Business

In one of those frequent anti-car threads, I posted the only empirical evidence I could find on how charging for parking reduced business:

Do parking fees affect retail sales? Evidence from Starbucks

"Parking meters are a common feature of urban areas, yet their economic impacts are not well understood. Local governments use meters to raise revenue and to ration scarce parking spaces. On-street parking, however, is seldom priced at the market rate. When inefficiently priced, parking meters may negatively affect the businesses and individuals they are intended to serve. This paper uses a quasi-experimental research design and an observational data set to assess metered parking policy. Sharp twice-daily changes in parking meter enforcement provide a comparison of customer traffic to a popular retail area in free and metered parking environments. Regression discontinuity results suggest that when there is an excess supply of parking (i.e., many spaces are vacant), a small 50 cent per-hour parking fee deters commerce. At two separate Starbucks establishments, the meter fee reduced customer traffic by almost 30%. However, when there is excess demand for parking (i.e., all spaces are constantly occupied), there is no evidence that meters help to increase customer traffic. These results suggest that sub-optimal meter pricing can impose substantial costs on nearby businesses."

The anti-car people weren't happy. Silly cope which didn't even attempt to make an argument aside, one anti-car person claimed that I was misunderstanding the study, and claimed that reducing the number of carpark spots AND charging for them made for an optimal outcome.

I had to explain the study's findings in more detail to him:

"If there're vacant spaces, charging for parking reduces business, because 30% of people don't like paying for parking and people rather not visit than pay for parking

If there're no vacant spaces, charging for parking does not reduce business, because though the people who don't like paying for parking stop visiting, those who are willing to pay for it still visit

A numerical example will help

In all scenarios, 100 people are interested in visiting Business X

Scenario A: there're 120 parking spots and they don't charge for parking
Result: All 100 people visit Business X, because there's lots of parking

Scenario B: there're 120 parking spots and they charge for parking
Result: Only 70 people visit Business X, because 30% of people don't want to pay for parking. Charging for parking reduces business by 30%

In Scenario A vs B, charging for parking reduces business by 30%

Scenario C: there're 50 parking spots and they don't charge for parking
Result: Only 50 people visit Business X. 50 more people want to visit Business X but cannot, because there isn't enough parking.

Scenario D: there're 50 parking spots and they charge for parking
Result: Only 50 people visit Business X. 30 people don't want to visit Business X because they must pay for parking. 20 people want to visit Business X but cannot, because there isn't enough parking.

In Scenario C vs D, charging for parking does not reduce business by 30%

Now, consider what happens if Business X takes your suggestion and reduces the number of parking spaces available AND charges for them

Scenario E: there're 10 parking spots and they charge for parking
Result: Only 10 people visit Business X. 30 people don't want to visit Business X because they must pay for parking. 60 people want to visit Business X but cannot, because there isn't enough parking.

Or you can also compare Scenarios B and D - in Scenario B, 70 people visit Business X but in Scenario D, only 50 do.

Of course, whether it is more profitable to have more parking spaces depends on the cost of land, and the fraction of people deterred by parking charges depends on how much people want to visit the place (and alternative transport and parking options).

But to pretend that there're no costs to reducing and/or charging for parking spaces is wrong."

Another anti-car person claimed that the study only looked at customer entries to Starbucks and didn't look at sales figures, pedestrian or cyclist traffic, and that other businesses weren't studied so they might have different results from coffee places. He also cited a City of Toronto study claiming removing parking to create bike lanes improved business.

I had to point out that he was wrong, since the study looked at customers patronising the establishments, not vehicle traffic, and that Gap, Banana Republic (clothing) and Rite-Aid (drug store) were also studied, and for Rite-Aid, parking becoming free increased customer traffic. If his claim were right, cyclists/pedestrians would have to spend a lot more than drivers, since in the case where customer traffic fell by 30%, the average customer in the scenario where parking was chargeable would've had to spend 43% more than in the scenario where parking was free for the establishment to have the same revenue in both instances. Which means that cyclists/pedestrians would've had to spend a lot more than 43% more than drivers (since even in the case where parking was chargeable, many of the customers would've still been drivers - unless he was claiming that somehow, paying for parking means drivers would spend more).

Evidently he did not know that Starbucks was not just a takeout coffee place, but a third space. In any event, for businesses where customers would linger, the expected detrimental effect of charging for parking would be more - because the longer you spend in a shop, the more you need to pay for parking (vs free parking with a $0 cost).

There were also methodological problems with the Toronto study (it was done by the City rather than professional researchers, and wasn't peer reviewed, and had very rudimentary controls). If you dig into the PDF with spending data, one will notice that (methodological issues with omitted variables aside), there was a bigger growth in transactional volume (value of customer spend) city-wide than in the pilot area and a bigger decrease in per-transaction size in the area than in the city as a whole, and we don't know if the differences are statistically significant.

In any event, the Toronto study does not prove that removing parking increased sales (indeed, one city PDF that's linked says that there was an "addition of off-street lot parking spaces and higher utilization in the off-street lots", so it looks like there was still enough parking - which coheres with the study I posted).

More from the paper:

"Consider the following outline of a parking model (developed more fully later in the paper), which illustrates two potential effects of fees on retailers. When parking is saturated (i.e., spaces are used at capacity), per-minute fees generate turnover, which in turn increases customer flow. But increased flow comes at the cost of reducing average shopping time per customer. If purchases increase at a decreasing rate with shopping time, the negative sales effect of shorter shopping times is more than offset by the increase in the number of customers, raising total retail sales. Thus, an increase in parking charges could actually help nearby retailers, which is a potentially surprising conclusion.

However, when parking is not saturated (i.e., empty parking spaces are freely available), the higher charges do not raise the availability of parking and thus do not increase customer flow. By reducing shopping time, higher charges reduce individual purchases and thus total retail sales. This negative effect is compounded when higher charges deter consumers from initiating shopping trips, amplifying the sales reduction. Thus, the beneficial effect of parking charges for retailers under saturated conditions is likely to be reversed when parking is not saturated.

The regression results indicate that small per-minute parking fees can have a substantial effect on commerce. The 10:00 AM imposition of fees, which occurs at a non-saturated time, reduces customer traffic in accordance with expectations. At two separate coffee shops, a relatively small 50 cent per hour meter fee reduced customer flow by almost 30%. However, the 7:00 PM cessation of parking charges, which occurs during the saturated period, had almost no effect on customer traffic at two clothing stores and was associated with a small increase in traffic at a drug store. These findings are contrary to the expectation that a reduction in parking fees should result in a decrease in customer flow. Also, the regression discontinuity results are subject to one important caveat: the measured effect of fees on customer traffic should be interpreted as local effects that are specific to the observed neighborhood at specific times of day.

These negative findings do not support the argument that higher parking charges benefit retailers by increasing customer flow. The only way such an effect could occur is if the higher charges raise customer traffic under saturated conditions, and the evidence in this paper does not support such an impact. In sum, the results suggest that conventional metered parking policy can have significant negative effects on nearby commerce...

Under saturated parking conditions, increased meter fees were hypothesized to generate turnover and thus increase customer flow. Evidence from the evening observation period does not support this hypothesis as the fees had almost no effect when parking was saturated. Customer traffic at the Gap and Banana Republic was constant before and after the cessation of fees, while traffic at Rite-Aid only increased by a small amount. The subsections below analyze the empirical evidence further...

Although one would expect that fees reduce customer traffic in non-saturated conditions, the magnitude of the reduction is surprising, especially given the small size of the fee.

However, an important qualification should be noted before concluding that parking fees in non-saturated conditions harm the Starbucks corporation. As coffee from Starbucks C is a perfect substitute for coffee from the other stores, customers arriving after 9:57 AM may simply drive one extra mile to make their purchase from the location with free parking. So although fees reduce customer traffic and may harm sales at an individual store, the overall impact of fees on multi-store sales may be smaller if people can easily adjust the location for their coffee purchases. But this effect would only be large if the parking fees outweigh the cost of fuel, which is unlikely as gasoline prices were approximately $4.00 per gallon when this data was collected. The empirical evidence provides only weak support of a location-adjustment effect...

In sum, these findings do not support the claim that parking fees help increase customer flow. Furthermore, the empirical evidence suggests that even in nearly saturated conditions (say 95% occupancy rate), modest fees may still reduce customer flow...

In sum, for both saturated and non-saturated parking environ- ments the empirical evidence does not support the conclusion that parking meters help increase customer flow and thereby increase retail sales.

The results of this study suggest that parking meters with demand- invariant fees are a poor tool for managing access to popular locations. There is no empirical evidence to support the claim that fees benefit nearby businesses by increasing customer traffic. In non-saturated periods, the fees are not needed to ration parking spaces, and the evidence shows that Belmont Shore's small meter fees decreased customer traffic by a significant amount. The magnitude of the effect — a 25–30% reduction in customer entries at Starbucks — is remarkable, despite the small size of the fee, which amounts to less than 10 cents for customers purchasing coffee to go. Also, contrary to expectations, this study found no evidence that parking meters help generate turnover during periods of high demand. When parking was saturated, Belmont Shore's small fees did not increase customer flow at nearby retailers...

Compounding the case against demand-invariant parking fees is the fact that a significant reduction in local sales tax receipts would likely accompany any decrease in sales. Considering the small size of the parking fee, a reduction in tax receipts could potentially negate the revenue generating function of the meters. Together, the results suggest that conventional meters are a poor instrument for rationing scarce parking spaces. Thus, the results support the case for more flexible parking fees, ones that vary over time and location. Such parking policies and technologies have been employed successfully in places like San Francisco and could be expanded to other cities in the future"

Related:

How Parking Reform Is Helping Transform American Cities - "The common problem with curb parking is that it is too cheap. All-day parkers (often, local employees) arrive first thing in the morning and take the best spots, leaving visitors to cruise in frustration — a phenomenon that appears to account for a sizable share of traffic in congested places. In San Francisco, meter rates now rise and fall once a month according to how hard it is to find a parking space, with the goal of a free spot on every block. To sweeten the deal for local merchants who fear losing clientele to suburban shopping centers, some cities have re-invested meter money in local improvements... One recent federal study projected that if employees who get free parking at work received an equivalent bonus for not using that parking, traffic in major cities would fall by 10 percent, with equivalent drops in fuel consumption, pollution, and emissions. Free parking is also a strong predictor of car ownership; paid parking is a strong predictor of transit use. If you want less traffic, parking policy is the place to start."
Somehow I doubt they proved causation for free/paid parking and car ownership/transit use

The evidence base for parking policies—a review - "van der Schaaf (2002) reports on a major implementation of city centre parking restraint in Amsterdam which forms part of a large area-wide mobility management plan. Most of the area inside the inner ring road is now subject to significant parking restraint. Car mileage in the historical core has reduced and public transport trips to the centre have increased. However, van der Schaaf notes that the congestion problem has migrated to areas outside the ring road due, in part, to the absence of strong land use policies and parking restraint in these areas. It is suggested that some employment has left the urban core for the periphery (van der Schaaf, 2002) although empirical supporting data is not provided and this phenomenon may be the result of the other non-transport factors described by Gerrard et al. (2002)... Still and Simmonds (2000) reviewed the empirical and modelling evidence on the relationship between parking restraint policies and urban vitality. The study did not find substantial direct evidence of the impacts of parking policy on land-use as such responses are only likely to be seen in the long-term and ‘‘parking restraint policies have not been previously implemented with consistency and longevity’’ (Still and Simmonds, 2000, p. 291). The authors found that ‘‘behavioural and attitudinal studies tend to conclude that strong relationships exist (between parking provision and economic vitaility). Aggregate statistical studies on the contrary find only a very weak relationship’’ (Still and Simmonds, 2000, p. 313). Modelling work conducted to augment the study suggested that where strong parking restraint is introduced in the city centre but not elsewhere in the city this can have negative impacts on the city centre."

blog comments powered by Disqus
Related Posts Plugin for WordPress, Blogger...

Latest posts (which you might not see on this page)

powered by Blogger | WordPress by Newwpthemes